Real World Economics: St. Paul’s medical debt plan is sensible, despite the tradeoffs

Must Read

St. Paul prevails in legal fight to raze, replace historic Hamline-Midway Library

Following 16 months of litigation, a Ramsey County district judge has given the town of St. Paul the go-ahead...

St. Paul-based Securian Financial lays off 58 employees across departments

Securian Financial has notified 58 employees — roughly 2% of its total workforce — that their roles with the...

U.S. Rep. Betty McCollum seeks thirteenth term in rematch with May Lor Xiong in 4th District

Longtime St. Paul Democratic U.S. Rep. Betty McCollum is in search of one other term in Minnesota’s Fourth Congressional...

Edward Lotterman

At times issues which are minor and short-term in themselves can illuminate broader tradeoffs or principles.

That’s true for the mayor and city council of St. Paul selecting to spend $1.1 million to wipe out city residents’ unpaid debt to medical providers price a nominal value of over $100 million.

This can profit some 43,000 city residents, improving their credit and thus their access to modern payment systems and to needed services.

It’s proposed as a one-time deal that’s presupposed to not burden city taxpayers. The funds come from the American Rescue Plan, the large federal spending play passed within the COVID-era first weeks of the Biden administration. This was intended to reduce recessionary drops in national output and household incomes because the epidemic throttled the U.S. market economy.

St. Paul got $166 million and has to spend the small fraction not yet used.

To place things in context, $1.1 million is 0.6% of the funds St Paul received via this laws. It’s 0.14% of the town’s budget for the approaching fiscal 12 months. And, from a federal budget standpoint, it’s 0.06% of the effective multinational engine maker Cummins goes to pay the feds for engines built to cheat on pollution controls. And this outlay roughly equals the associated fee of manufacturing corn on three of the 12,000 square miles of the crop grown in Minnesota. In other words, whether it’s a small or great amount relies on one’s perspective.

The first query will not be just whether it’s idea or not. It’s how good an idea it’s in comparison with other things the cash is likely to be used for. Estimating that’s the knotty core of all public finance.

Yet it is beneficial to start out from a previous query. Why does such debt exist, why is it an issue and to whom?

The reply to this query is that the debt is an end result of the U.S. system of health care financing that manages to be each highly “inefficient” — in how economists use the term, judging advantages gained against resources used — and at the identical time highly unjust. Politically we don’t want “socialized medicine,” so we ended up with a system during which most households get some type of medical insurance, either public or private, while a nonnegligible minority has to pay out of pocket.

It’s a fancy system with huge administrative costs shot through with perverse incentives. One is to make use of “price discrimination” to a fare thee well. To economists, “price discrimination” means charging different prices to customers with different “elasticities of demand” — or the extent to which price affects the sale of a product. Necessities like health care are very inelastic, that’s, people proceed to demand care at the same time as price gets very high.

Nearly all of the population are insulated from direct buying because they’re covered by private insurance or a public plan like Minnesota Care, Medicare or, in my case, the U.S. military Tricare. These plans negotiate large discounts from the artificially-high nominal prices for treatments.

But out-of-pocket patients are billed for the complete sticker price. Many cannot pay, and billions in unpaid medical debt accrues. Providers spend money on collection agencies but much debt is written off eventually. This all aspects back into the nominal or list prices, which then go up. But within the meantime, a person or family with unpaid debt on someone’s books, be it health provider or collection agency, then finds it difficult to get home or automobile loans or perhaps a bank card — which is important for day-to-day transactions in a contemporary economy. So the unpaid debt trickles through the larger economy.

Unpaid medical debt thus is a big national problem that makes life even harder for those amongst us already living difficult lives. There are programs starting to handle the issue and Minnesota is ahead of the curve with an agreement on the a part of major providers to not report medical debt to credit scoring agencies. And there are NGOs corresponding to RIP Medical Debt, a Recent York-based nonprofit fostering local government initiatives — including St. Paul’s. It can function an intermediary between the town and health providers to discover debt that will be most useful to erase.

Now for some standard public finance questions:

Is there a spillover profit to society as a complete beyond the direct value received from benefitting households? Probably, to the extent that having higher credit may facilitate people being more productive, with the ability to get jobs that a adverse credit rating might need kept them out of or starting small businesses or buying or renting higher housing. This net profit to the general economy probably exists but could be very difficult to quantify.

Could or would the issue be solved by market forces without the motion of presidency? Probably not, or not yet, although there are emerging “mediating structures” of the kind described by sociologist Peter Berger and theologian Richard J. Neuhaus. These include the nonprofit with which St. Paul will work and the ad hoc cooperation that secured the 2021 agreement of major Minnesota providers to not report bad medical debt.

Does this system create perverse incentives? Well-meaning government policies like this often do. Rent controls deter investment in recent inexpensive housing and discourage home ownership. Money payments or tax incentives by a city motivate migration of individuals and businesses from other cities. But on this case, it’s difficult to assume that many individuals will suddenly move to St. Paul to get debts erased or determine to get more costly medical procedures because at some future time, payments for these shall be easier to default on. So yes, while there could also be some contrary incentives, they don’t leap out at us.

Will a supposed one-time motion create expectations of an ongoing program that can entail ongoing city budget outlays? It is a real phenomenon. A one-time extension of free lunches to all students with COVID money has grow to be a everlasting program that can cost the state of Minnesota greater than expected. That is currently a hot debate at state budget levels. (I support the everlasting lunch program despite cost overruns). But it surely seems much less likely this could occur with medical debt, partially since it involves a much smaller fraction of the population.

Will beneficiaries be chosen fairly if some who potentially might be aided get shut out? Will the standards be income-needs based? That is a difficulty for a lot of such programs. The free-lunch program is open to all. Within the St. Paul plan, much relies on the competence and goodwill of RIP Medical Debt and participating providers.

Finally, can we know that spending $1.1 million erasing bad medical debt will do more to enhance the well-being of more people as a complete than alternative uses for the cash? How can we measure that? Although it’s a small fraction of the town budget, that was the priority of the one St. Paul council member who voted against the plan. It’s an issue that bedevils all public spending. And in addition much private-sector spending, especially in large corporations. Stock buybacks vs. capital investment? But additionally consider households: A $100 restaurant dinner for 2 could also be enjoyable, but it surely also represents per week’s price of groceries for those self same two people. Are the trade offs price it?

The very best thing, or course, could be a national restructuring of health financing that will provide take care of all without debt accumulating for some. But that has proved a bridge too far for a long time now. That mustn’t deter our higher levels of presidency from trying again, or our city from acting now.

St. Paul economist and author Edward Lotterman will be reached at stpaul@edlotterman.com.






IT’S HERE! DON’T MISS OUT!

I Am Twin Cities

Get Free Subscription to our latest content

LEAVE A REPLY

Please enter your comment!
Please enter your name here

Latest News

St. Paul prevails in legal fight to raze, replace historic Hamline-Midway Library

Following 16 months of litigation, a Ramsey County district judge has given the town of St. Paul the go-ahead...

St. Paul-based Securian Financial lays off 58 employees across departments

Securian Financial has notified 58 employees — roughly 2% of its total workforce — that their roles with the corporate are being eliminated in...

U.S. Rep. Betty McCollum seeks thirteenth term in rematch with May Lor Xiong in 4th District

Longtime St. Paul Democratic U.S. Rep. Betty McCollum is in search of one other term in Minnesota’s Fourth Congressional District and again faces May...

Believed to have been the oldest working nurse in Minnesota, Joyce Gimmestad retired at 88. She reflects on 7 many years in healthcare

Joyce Gimmestad hoped to succeed in 90 before retiring from being a nurse. Still, she retired on June 22, at 88, attributable to a...

Family of 83-year-old St. Paul man killed in hit-and-run: ‘We’ll forgive you. … Please turn yourself in’

For 30 years, John Bidon took each day runs around Lake Phalen near his St. Paul home. He’d stretch it out to 5 miles...

More Articles Like This